Bribing Business to Hire Workers
A big-push program the size of the Tennessee Valley
Authority would be unthinkable today. But smaller big pushes are very common,
in the form of a myriad of federal and state subsidies to attract private
investment to struggling communities. Virtually every time a company announces
plans for a new headquarters, a lab, or a large production facility somewhere
in the United States, the bidding begins. States compete aggressively by
offering larger and larger enticements in the form of tax breaks, subsidized
loans, local infrastructure, export assistance and financing, workforce
training, and area marketing.
These subsidies can be incredibly large.
Panasonic recently received more than $100 million ($125,000 per job) to move
its North American headquarters to Newark, while Electrolux was given $180
million ($150,000 per job) in tax abatements for its new establishment in
Memphis. Mercedes received a $250 million incentive package ($165,000 per job)
for locating in Vance, Alabama. Total state spending on local economic
development amounts to $40 billion a year, significantly more than the
cumulative federal spending for the Tennessee Valley Authority over its thirty
years of government subsidies. These subsidies are one of the rare issues that
Democrats and Republicans tend to agree on. Although their rhetoric about
government intervention sounds different, blue and red states both engage in
efforts to bribe businesses to come to their jurisdictions. Rick Perry’s $200
million “Emerging Technology Fund” for Texas companies is similar to
initiatives in California, New York, and Massachusetts. The federal loan
guarantee program that Solyndra took advantage of was started in 2005 under
George W. Bush and was expanded in 2009 by Barack Obama.
While politicians and the companies they
subsidize usually extol the benefits of these deals, critics complain that they
are a huge waste of public money. Is spending $150,000 per job really the best
way to help the residents of Memphis? What if we just wrote checks to those
residents instead? With two colleagues, I have studied what happens to local
communities when their bid to attract a large employer by offering subsidies is
successful. When firms are considering where to open
a large plant, they typically begin by looking at dozens of possible locations.
They narrow the list to roughly ten sites, from which two or three finalists
are selected. In our study we compared the experience of the counties that the
company ultimately chose (the winner) with the runner-up counties (the losers).
For example, when BMW decided to open a new plant in the United States in the
1990s, the decision of where to locate it came down to two finalists:
Greenville-Spartanburg, South Carolina, and Omaha, Nebraska. BMW chose
Greenville-Spartanburg, partly because of an incentives package worth $115 million.
In this case and others, the losers were counties that had survived a long
selection process but narrowly lost the competition. They can therefore tell us
how the winner county would have fared if it had decided not to bid.
Our data show that in the years leading up to
such a bidding war, winners and losers were similar in terms of employment,
salaries, and productivity. But afterward, winners experienced a surge in
productivity. These productivity gains, which appeared to reflect knowledge
spillovers, were particularly large for existing plants that shared similar
labor and technology pools with the new plant. We concluded that by making
existing producers more productive, a new plant generated an important
benefit—a positive externality—for the rest of the establishments in the
county. This higher productivity led to more jobs and higher wages. Thus the
provision of subsidies might be seen as a way to internalize this externality.
While the theory is clear, in practice these
policies do not always work the way they are supposed to. The provision of the
subsidy should be commensurate with the magnitude of the social benefit. But
when dozens of similar counties are desperate to attract investment from
outside, their bids often become so generous that they can exceed the social
benefits to the community. Mayors and governors have an incentive to bring the
new company to town, no matter what the cost. When they are successful,
front-page stories in local newspapers tend to focus on the hundreds of future
local jobs, not on the fine print of the financial packages offered. When they
are unsuccessful, local politicians are lambasted for not doing enough for the
local economy. All of this can lead local governments to overbid. In such a
case, the only winners are the owners of the company being courted, since state
and local governments end up stuck with the bill. And even when these subsidies
make economic sense for a particular county, they do not always make sense for
the country as a whole, as competition among municipalities for a given company
can turn out to be a zero-sum game for the nation.
Post Comment
Aucun commentaire