The Economics of Poverty Traps and Big Pushes
We have just seen the promise and the pitfalls of
policies to foster local economic growth by increasing the supply of skilled
workers in a city. The alternative approach is to try to increase the demand
for labor by attracting employers. This often amounts to offering targeted
incentives to innovative companies to locate in a struggling community, in the
hope of forming a cluster that in the long run becomes self-sustaining. Once a
successful industrial cluster is under way, it tends to strengthen over time.
Its labor market and the market for specialized business services become even
thicker, and its knowledge spillovers become even stronger. The difficult part,
of course, is jump-starting the cluster.
In 2005, Ping Wang was facing a similar problem.
He had been chairman of the economics department at Washington University in
St. Louis for only a few months, but he quickly realized that the department
was in trouble. Wash U. offers an excellent undergraduate program, ranked just
below the Ivy League schools, and attracts smart students from all over the
country. Unlike its Ivy League competitors, however, Wash U. has never been
particularly strong in economics. When Wang became chairman, the department had
been stuck for years near the lower part of academic rankings. It simply did
not have many professors actively engaged in research.
For a university, there is much to be gained
from a strong economics department. Economics tends to be a popular major,
because it offers good career prospects. Unlike many other academic fields,
economics matters to people outside academia, and economists’ research is often
cited in newspapers and television. While academic economists’ salaries are
considerably higher than, say, those of physicists or biologists, economists
are cheap for universities, since they do not need expensive labs or
sophisticated scientific instruments.
The problem with transforming a sleepy,
third-rate economics department into a top-notch research powerhouse, Wang
quickly realized, was that academics are kind of like high-tech companies: they
tend to be productive and innovative when they are surrounded by smart
colleagues with whom they can exchange ideas. Left alone, they tend to
stagnate. Thus departments that are already strong tend to become stronger over
time, because the presence of productive researchers is attractive to other
productive researchers, and departments that are weak tend to get weaker for
the same reason. No good academic wants to be the first to move to a weak
department. It is not just about prestige; it is about actual productivity.
Economists who study developing countries call
this situation a poverty trap. Wang realized that
there was only one way to break out of this trap: he needed a “big push”
strategy. What he did was unprecedented. He called up two academic stars at
other universities and made them an offer they simply could not refuse: a
yearly salary in the vicinity of $600,000. The gamble paid off. The two stars
quit their jobs at more prestigious universities and moved to St. Louis. Now
that the department had two stars, other economists began to find the place
attractive and accepted Wang’s offers there, albeit at normal salaries. As more
good economists went there, the department became even more attractive. Wash U.
jumped in the rankings. Wang had broken out of the poverty trap. Unfortunately,
this positive feedback loop broke down in 2008, when the financial crisis
severely diminished Wash U.’s endowment and forced the department to scale back
its hiring.
In essence, a city stuck in a poverty trap
faces the same challenge. It is trapped by its past. The only way to move a
city from a bad equilibrium to a good one is with a big push: a coordinated
policy that breaks the impasse and simultaneously brings skilled workers,
employers, and specialized business services to a new location. Only the
government can initiate these big-push policies, because only the government
has the ability to coordinate the individual actors—the workers and
employers—to get the agglomeration process going. The idea is to provide public
subsidies for those who are willing to move first but then stop the subsidies
after the process becomes self-sustaining, in much the same way that Wash U.
was willing to overpay the first two people hired but not later ones. The
benefits of big-push policies are potentially huge, because declining
communities can, in principle, be brought back to life.
But the track record of these policies is mixed.
To succeed, the push needs to be really big. It also
needs to be decisive and sustained, and, most important, the subsidies must
target the right beneficiaries. As the story of Wash U. shows, the cost can be
high and the success only temporary.
The first and most important big push ever
attempted in the history of the United States was the Tennessee Valley
Authority (TVA), created in the midst of the Great Depression to lift a
desperately poor region out of poverty. According to Franklin Roosevelt—never
prone to understatement—the program was intended to modernize the regional
economy by “touching and giving life to all forms of human concerns.” In
practice, this meant investing in large-scale infrastructure programs,
particularly electricity-generating dams, whose power was used to electrify the
region and boost local productivity; an extensive network of new roads; a
650-mile navigation canal; schools; and flood control systems. A smaller
portion of the funds was devoted to malaria prevention, reforestation,
educational programs, and health clinics. The scale of the program was
enormous, far beyond anything attempted before or since. Between 1933 and 1958,
$30 billion from U.S. taxpayers poured into the region.
At the program’s peak, in 1950, the annual federal subsidy to the region was
$625 per household. After 1958 the federal government began to scale back its
investment, and the TVA became a largely self-sustaining entity.
This approach to economic development is based on
the intuitive notion that public monies can jump-start a local economy trapped
in poverty. But critics on both the right and the left have lambasted such initiatives,
either as big government overreach or top-down control of local communities. In
an influential 1984 article in the New York Review of Books,
the progressive urban thinker Jane Jacobs wrote a scathing critique of big-push
policies, including the TVA, arguing that it is an unnatural way to foster
local economies and concluding that “in practice, they work miserably.”
How can we assess these place-based policies in a
rigorous way? The real test is not whether they create jobs during the push.
The fact that an inflow of money temporarily increases economic activity in an
area is hardly a sign that the money was well spent. Instead we need to look at
whether the publicly financed seed can eventually generate a privately
supported cluster that is large enough to become self-sustaining. The idea is
that the government-provided investment carries the local economy past the
tipping point but not any further. At that point the forces of agglomeration
take over, continuing to attract businesses and workers well after the
subsidies end.
My colleague Pat Kline and I conducted a
careful study of the TVA initiative and found that the program was successful
in generating an industrial revolution in an area that had been largely rural
up to that point. During the big-push years of 1933
to 1958, manufacturing jobs in the region grew much faster than they did in the
rest of the country, as companies found the cheap electricity and easy
transportation attractive. Manufacturing jobs kept growing faster after the
federal subsidies dried up. Even in 2000, more than forty years after the end
of the federal transfers, manufacturing jobs in the region were growing faster
than those in comparable parts of the South, although the effect is now slowing
down and will probably disappear soon. While the program was successful in
moving the region from a low-productivity sector (agriculture) to a
high-productivity sector (manufacturing), it did not succeed in raising local
wages in any significant way. The reason is simple: as more and more jobs were
created, more and more workers moved there from the rest of the South to take
advantage of improved economic conditions. This increase in the supply of labor
effectively offset the increase in demand.
The fundamental challenge with policies such as
the TVA is that for them to be successful, local policymakers must be able to
pick promising companies to invest in. They need to be a little like venture
capitalists. In this sense, FDR had it easy. When manufacturing was the engine
of job growth and prosperity depended on infrastructure and cheap energy, the
recipe for development was obvious. The level of industrial development in the
Tennessee Valley was so low that it did not matter too much whether an aluminum
smelter, a steel factory, or a chemical factory opened its doors. But today the
most important determinant of success for local communities is human capital,
and making the right call is much harder. Should a county spend all its money
attracting a new nanotech lab, or should it go for Amazon’s latest computer
farm? A solar-panel R&D facility or a biotech lab? Even professional
venture capitalists have a hard time predicting which industries and companies
will succeed. For mayors of struggling municipalities, this challenge can prove
insurmountable.
Indeed, looking at the map of America’s major
innovation clusters, it is hard to find an example of one that was spawned by a
big push. No local politician set out to create Silicon Valley. And we have
seen in the cases of Seattle, Boston, San Diego, and Los Angeles, the success
of an original anchor company was typically the seed that grew into a high-tech
cluster.
The same is true for smaller, more specialized
clusters, arguably a more realistic goal for struggling communities. Consider
Portland, Oregon; Boise; and Kansas City, three small high-tech hubs anchored
by semiconductors, general high tech, and animal health and nutrition science,
respectively. Although small, these are dynamic
centers: Portland and Boise produce almost as many patents per capita as
Boston. None of these hubs were planned. The opening of Intel’s semiconductor
facility in 1976 jump-started Portland’s high-tech sector. The seed for Boise
was planted in 1973, when Hewlett-Packard moved its printer division there. Life
science R&D in Kansas City can be traced back to the 1950s, when Ewing
Marion Kauffman started his pharmaceutical lab. As pointed out in a recent
Brookings Institution study, little of the high-tech presence in these cities
resulted from aggressive recruitment of companies by local governments.
Other parts of the world have seen some
success. Ireland used a deliberate big-push policy to build up
human-capital-intensive sectors that previously did not exist. Through
aggressive tax incentives and other enticements, it created important clusters
in high tech and finance, although the country’s recent financial crisis throws
into question the sustainability of such policies. Israel’s high-tech cluster,
one of the most dynamic in the world, is highly dependent on the country’s
military. Although the Israeli government did not set out to create a local
high-tech sector, its need for innovative defense technologies and specialized
human capital indirectly fostered a private sector that later became globally
competitive.
Perhaps the clearest example of big-push success
is Taiwan, which transformed its rural economy into an advanced one with a
dynamic innovation sector through a large-scale policy of government-sponsored
research in the 1960s and 1970s. The program succeeded in bringing top Chinese
scientists back from the United States and establishing a cluster of publicly
supported R&D that eventually became thick enough to sustain private
companies. This is one of those rare instances in which policymakers turned out
to be good venture capitalists. While they did bet on several failed
technologies, they also bet on semiconductors very early on. Semiconductors
quickly became the core of Taiwan’s high-tech sector and arguably one of its
engines of prosperity. More recently, Taiwan’s high-tech cluster has been
embracing newer technologies, including life sciences. But Taiwan might just be
the exception that proves the rule.
Post Comment
Aucun commentaire