Gentrification and Its Discontents
Just as improvements in air quality can have unintended
consequences, a stronger labor market can sometimes have a dark side. Higher
real estate prices can displace the poor, significantly altering the mix of
residents in a community. Eventually these changes can affect a city’s very
identity. For example, think of Boston in the 1970s. Its economy was in
terrible condition, bogged down by an old manufacturing base and high
unemployment. But over the past three decades it has flourished, thanks to jobs
in innovation and finance. The transformation was not just economic but also
demographic and cultural. It resulted in a profound remaking of the social
texture of the city, its urban form, and its quality of life. While many of
these changes were for the better, there were also significant social costs. Many
longtime residents ended up being priced out of their own neighborhoods. And
even those who stayed were not spared, as the character of some communities
shifted in sudden and sometimes uncomfortable ways. Those who moved to Boston
between 1990 and 2010 tended to have college degrees and professional
occupations. Those who moved out tended to have low levels of schooling and
nonprofessional jobs. The lifestyles, values, and social identities of the two
groups could not have been more different.
The debate about the costs of local economic
development can get acrimonious. Local activists in cities such as Cambridge,
Berkeley, Washington, D.C., and Santa Monica love to hate this sort of economic
change, arguing that it should be stopped at any cost because it ends up
hurting communities. While it is clear that there are costs, it is useful to
clarify who bears them and what the best way to minimize them is.
As we have seen, original homeowners benefit
from gentrification. It is important to recognize that this group can be
socially quite distinct from the gentrifiers—the college-educated
professionals, the innovators, the entrepreneurs. Almost by definition, a
gentrifying neighborhood is one in which many of the original residents,
including the property owners, are not particularly wealthy. Take the Mission
District, the neighborhood of San Francisco where I live. It is one of the
areas of the city that has been most affected by the influx of college-educated
high-tech professionals. Since it is close to the freeway, many workers in
Silicon Valley who prefer an urban lifestyle end up here. Remarkably, the
people who are benefiting most from this influx of high-tech workers are the
largely Latino homeowners who have been selling their property to the newcomers—people
like the Mexican American couple who owned a nice two-story Victorian near my
house that had been in the family for decades. They decided to sell it for
$950,000 and move to the suburbs, where they could buy a similar-sized house
for half the price and live off the balance.
What about all the other residents, people who
never had any property to begin with? In many large urban areas, most residents
are renters and are therefore hit hard by an increase in cost of living. This
is especially painful for the elderly and those with low incomes who end up
relinquishing their houses, memories, neighbors, and social networks—in a word,
much of their lives—and have to start from scratch somewhere else. What should
we do to protect them from sudden displacement?
The typical reaction in many communities is
stringent land-use regulation designed to slow down socioeconomic change. These
laws tend to come in two flavors. The first focuses on commercial real estate
and seeks to moderate gentrification by limiting the number of new office
buildings. One of the most extreme cases is the city of Berkeley, which in an
effort to protect “good blue-collar jobs” has effectively stunted high-tech
growth in the entire west side of the city. Large parts of eastern San Francisco
are also slated for light manufacturing in the vain hope that the industry will
bounce back. The second kind focuses on residential real estate and seeks to
limit new market-rate construction, particularly in transforming neighborhoods.
In effect, the first kind seeks to limit the inflow of new employers in the
innovation sector, while the second seeks to limit the inflow of new residents.
Both aim to reduce private investment with the intent of preserving the
existing economic and cultural demographics.
In my view, both approaches are misguided and
unlikely to be effective at managing gentrification. Constraining new high-tech
office buildings amounts to reducing the number of jobs that a city can create,
because it is quite unlikely that factories will open in the urban core of
cities like San Francisco and Santa Monica. Because of the multiplier and
spillover effects, this policy ends up hurting the very people it is intended
to help. Indeed, the most important lesson of the multiplier and spillover effects
is that unskilled workers in a city have much to gain from the fortunes of the
more skilled workers who live next door, as their very livelihoods often depend
on sustained growth in the innovation sector: more skilled residents in a city
mean more and better jobs for the less skilled. The policy also hurts
nonresidents. As we have seen, innovation hubs are among the most productive
areas in the United States, and this higher productivity attracts workers from
everywhere in the nation. This level of productivity cannot be easily
replicated elsewhere, because of the strong forces of agglomeration. Thus,
curtailing job creation in America’s innovation hubs is apt to result in a net
job loss for the country. It is a terrible waste of resources—one that makes
our unemployment rate worse.
Curtailing new residential developments also
makes little sense. It is the equivalent of creating jobs in a city but then
denying those jobs to any applicant who comes from somewhere else. Moreover, it
is likely to accelerate the displacement of poor residents, not to slow it
down. The reason is quite simple: rationing new housing in a city invariably
results in even higher real estate prices. It makes intuitive sense: if there
is high demand for housing in a city, reducing supply can only raise the price.
In a series of recent studies, the urban economist Ed Glaeser and various
collaborators have uncovered clear evidence that cities that adopt more
restrictive residential development policies invariably end up with higher housing
costs relative to wage levels. By contrast, cities
that are proactive in allowing urban housing development end up with lower
housing costs.
The real solution to the problem of
gentrification is exactly the opposite of restricting new residential development.
Instead of limiting new housing, innovation hubs should encourage it. If
managed correctly through smart growth policies, more housing does not mean
more sprawl and congestion, especially if it is concentrated in the urban core
and is accompanied by an expansion of the public transit system. These kinds of
progressive urban development policies can significantly mitigate the negative
effects of gentrification while promoting the serendipitous urban social
interactions that foster knowledge spillovers and innovation.
A good example is Seattle. When economic
conditions there began to improve, thanks to the expansion of high-tech jobs,
the city decided to increase the number of new housing units available to
families by allowing a significant amount of infill urban development—the type
of development that focuses on making an area denser by renovating existing
buildings and developing empty lots, thus avoiding sprawl. This increase in
supply kept real estate prices in check. While there clearly were price
increases, they were lower than those of cities like San Francisco and Boston,
which aggressively limit new housing. Essentially, this acted like a
redistribution mechanism that favored renters over homeowners. It meant that a
larger share of the wealth created by the rise of the local high-tech sector
went to the former group instead of the latter.
Seattle was also fortunate to have farsighted
business leaders. In contrast to those in most other American cities, major
retailers in Seattle decided to stay downtown. The Nordstrom family, together
with the other department stores at the time—most important, Frederick &
Nelson—wanted to head off the “exodus to the mall” phenomenon. This decision
encouraged urban planners to embrace a retail-based urban center, an unusual
move for American cities. Things would be very different today if Nordstrom had
fled. The simultaneous growth of high-tech jobs in and around the downtown area
and high-density housing in the city’s walkable neighborhoods reversed
middle-class flight from the city center and ultimately resulted in a lower
crime rate, vibrant cultural offerings, and new restaurants. As new residents
flocked to the urban core, public schools experienced noticeable improvements.
Test scores increased, and not just for those children who had well-educated
parents but also for children whose parents were less well educated and who had
non-high-tech jobs.
In the end, from the point of view of a city,
gentrification is a good problem to have, because it is a sign of economic
success and job growth. Dozens of decaying cities would love to have this
problem. At the same time, gentrification has serious social consequences. The
solution is not to discourage local job creation in the innovation sector,
hoping that manufacturing jobs will magically return. The solution is to manage
the process of economic growth in smart ways, to minimize the negative
consequences for the weakest residents and maximize the economic benefits for
all.
Post Comment
Aucun commentaire