The Surprising Relationship Between Inequality and Real Estate
The city of Norilsk, in northern Siberia, sits on
one of the earth’s largest reserves of nickel and platinum. Because nickel is a necessary component of steel,
Soviet planners made the development of Norilsk a priority during the 1930s.
Stalin sent a delegation of experts to explore the region, and the experts
reported that it would be difficult to attract workers to the city even by
offering premium wages. Conditions there were simply too hellish: extremely
cold temperatures, sometimes dropping to 45 degrees below zero, five months of
winter darkness, and a depressing landscape with virtually no vegetation made
it one of the most hostile environments on the planet. Although the precious
metal reserves in the area could, in theory, support many jobs, planners could
not come up with wages high enough to compensate workers for the horrible
living conditions. For someone like Stalin, of course, these were trivial
details. The feared state police, the NKVD, took over responsibility for the
development of the city and turned it into a gulag—a Soviet labor camp. About
100,000 political prisoners died building the city and laboring in its mines.
For decades the melting of the snowpack during the summer months revealed the
bones of workers who had perished.
In the Soviet Union, as in other communist
regimes in Eastern Europe and China, the state had the power to forcibly move
labor where it was needed. This gave rise to “artificial” cities such as
Norilsk—cities that would not have existed in a free society. In the United
States, workers are free to choose where they want to live. As we saw,
Americans take advantage of this and move around more than citizens of most
other countries. But there is a catch to this freedom. Living in places that
are perceived as more desirable, either because they offer a higher quality of
life or because they offer better jobs, tends to cost more. This is not
surprising. Unlike the Soviet economy, which assigned resources based on a
five-year plan, a market economy uses prices to allocate resources, and in this
case the scarce resource is land in attractive cities. If a city has great
weather, Americans tend to move there in large numbers, and in doing so they
bid up the price of real estate. Good weather may not have a sticker price, but
we implicitly pay for it, just as we pay for a nicer car or a larger TV. The
same is true for good public schools, low crime rates, and excellent local
restaurants. Every attractive feature of a city ends up being capitalized, at
least in part, into higher property values.
This simple observation has an unexpected
implication: those who actually end up benefiting from these features are not
necessarily those who are directly affected by them. Pollution levels in
Southern California have decreased dramatically over the past twenty years,
especially in Los Angeles, thanks to cleaner-burning gasoline and more
aggressive regulation. Some neighborhoods have experienced more improvements
than others, with ozone reductions ranging from 3 to 33 percent, depending on
the area. You might think that residents of the neighborhoods that have
experienced the largest pollution declines are the net winners, but that
depends on whether they own or rent their homes. One study found that the
larger the decline in pollution levels, the larger the increase in the
desirability of the neighborhood and therefore the higher the price of real
estate. In one low-income neighborhood, for example,
ozone concentrations declined by 24 percent but housing costs increased by 10.8
percent. The price increase benefited property owners, who became both
healthier and richer, but left renters healthier but poorer. Effectively, the
price change acted as an unintended redistribution mechanism that shifted some
of the benefits of air-quality improvements away from one group and toward
another.
The same principle applies when a city labor
market improves and local jobs are created. In the United States, we can see a
clear correlation between local labor market conditions and the cost of living.
Table 3 shows the metropolitan areas with the highest and lowest costs of
living today. To create the table, I used data on about one million households,
including both renters and homeowners, and data from the Bureau of Labor
Statistics on the price of consumer goods. To measure
cost of living, one needs to add up the local price of all the things consumed
by residents. How does the average American household spend its money? Most
people give the wrong answer. People tend to grossly overestimate the amount of
money they spend on food, gas, and groceries, probably because they purchase
these items regularly. In reality, the average American spends only 14 percent
of her income on food and beverages and 17 percent on transportation. This is
not very much. The other categories account for even less of the family budget:
apparel (3 percent), medical care (6 percent), recreation (5 percent),
education and communication (6 percent). (The way Americans divide their family
budget is fairly similar to the way families in other countries do, with the
main exception being Italian families, whose share of clothing expenditures is
double that of Americans.) By far the largest item in the budget is housing,
which accounts for 40 percent of spending. This means that most of the
differences in cost of living among metropolitan areas reflect differences in
the cost of housing, which in turn mostly reflect differences in the cost of
land. Other differences arise from the price of local services—things like
haircuts and restaurant meals—but these count considerably less, because their
share of the budget is smaller. Moreover, they too mostly reflect the cost of
land. For example, a haircut is more expensive in New York than in Dallas
because it costs more to rent a store and because the salary of the hairstylist
is higher to compensate for the higher cost of living. The same is true for
restaurant meals, therapy sessions, legal services, and nanny services.
TABLE 3: METROPOLITAN AREAS WITH HIGH AND LOW
COSTS OF LIVING
HIGHEST COST OF LIVING
|
LOWEST COST OF LIVING
|
1. San Jose, CA
|
271. Youngstown-Warren, OH/PA
|
2. Stamford, CT
|
272. Lima, OH
|
3. San Francisco–Oakland– Vallejo, CA
|
273. Terre Haute, IN
|
4. Santa Cruz, CA
|
274. Sharon, PA
|
5. Santa Barbara–Santa Maria–Lompoc, CA
|
275. St. Joseph, MO
|
6. Ventura–Oxnard–Simi Valley, CA
|
276. Lynchburg, VA
|
7. Boston, MA
|
277. Williamsport, PA
|
8. Honolulu, HI
|
278. Joplin, MO
|
9. Santa Rosa–Petaluma, CA
|
279. Brownsville–Harlingen–San Benito, TX
|
10. Salinas–Seaside–Monterey, CA
|
280. Duluth-Superior, MN/WI
|
11. New York–Northeastern NJ
|
281. Johnson City–Kingsport–Bristol, TN/VA
|
12. Washington, DC/MD/VA
|
282. Altoona, PA
|
13. Los Angeles–Long Beach, CA
|
283. Alexandria, LA
|
14. San Diego, CA
|
284. McAllen-Edinburg-Pharr-Mission, TX
|
15. Seattle-Everett, WA
|
285. Danville, VA
|
16. Trenton, NJ
|
286. Gadsden, AL
|
17. Bridgeport, CT
|
287. Anniston, AL
|
18. Fort Lauderdale–Hollywood–Pompano Beach, FL
|
288. Johnstown, PA
|
19. Austin, TX
|
|
20. Anchorage, AK
|
The table confirms that areas at the top of
the list tend to be the ones with the strongest labor markets—the ones where
wages and productivity are highest. San Jose is first, followed by Stamford and
San Francisco. Many American innovation hubs are in the top group—Boston,
Washington, D.C., San Diego, Seattle, and Austin. Anchorage is an exception,
because many of its necessities have to be imported. Because the data reflect
the entire metropolitan area, New York is only number eleven; taken alone, the city
of New York would be at the top of the list. By contrast, the areas with the
most affordable cost of living tend to have the weakest labor markets. At the
very bottom of the list we find Johnstown, Pennsylvania, a declining
manufacturing town, where the cost of living is four times lower than that of
San Jose. Other metro areas near the bottom include Anniston, Alabama; Gadsden,
Alabama; and Danville, Virginia. The relation between the strength of a labor
market and the cost of housing is not deterministic, but it depends on several
factors, including quality of life (better quality of life means higher housing
costs, all other things being equal) and how easy it is to build new houses to
accommodate increases in demand (easier housing development means lower costs).
These facts have a bearing on how we interpret
measures of inequality among workers and between cities. Let’s start with the
latter. When the labor market in a city strengthens, both workers’ earnings and
the cost of housing tend to increase. These increases have two separate effects
on residents. First, the increase in housing costs offsets some of the increase
in salaries. In cities like Johnstown, people have low nominal salaries, but
since mortgages are lower than elsewhere, an average salary has more purchasing
power. By contrast, people in New York, Washington, and Boston have higher
nominal salaries, but their effective salaries are not as high, because much of
their wage tends to go toward paying the mortgage. This helps explain why not everyone
has left Johnstown to move to Boston or New York. In practice, differences in
average earnings among U.S. cities adjusted for cost of living are about 25
percent smaller than unadjusted differences.10
However, this is not the end of the story. Just as with improvements in air quality, the effect of
a strong labor market on a family ultimately depends on whether that family
belongs to the 70 percent of Americans who own their homes or the 30 percent
who rent. Homeowners in strengthening labor markets gain twice, both because of
higher wages and because of higher property values. For them, the effect on
well-being is larger than the increase in purchasing power because of the capital
gains on their property. This highlights an unexpected conclusion: a
significant part of the wealth created by America’s dynamic innovation sector
accrues not just through the labor market but through the housing market. These
capital gains are an important channel through which residents of innovation
hubs benefit from the strength of their local economy. For renters, however,
the effect of higher earnings is tempered by the increase in their monthly
housing costs. Therefore, the ultimate effect on their well-being depends on
which of these two forces prevail. The larger the increase in wages and the
smaller the increase in rents, the better for them. As in the case of air
quality, the change in real estate prices effectively redistributes the wealth
created by job growth from one group to another. As we will soon discover,
local governments have the power to manage the increases in local cost of
living and can therefore determine whether homeowners or renters are the ones
to gain the most from a strengthening labor market.
This relationship between local labor markets
and cost of living also affects the way we think about inequality between
workers. Most of the public debate on inequality focuses on the striking
differences in salaries and incomes, but what really matters is how much people
can buy with their earnings. When economists started measuring inequality this
way, they found that the difference in consumption between rich and poor—from
groceries to clothes, electronics to health care—is not as large as the
difference in salary. How can the consumption gap
between the rich and the poor be smaller than the income gap?
An important explanation for this apparent
contradiction has to do with where people live. In recent research, I found
that since 1980, the amount that the typical college graduate spends on housing
has grown much faster than the amount the typical high school graduate spends. This trend does not just reflect better or larger
houses owned by college graduates. It mostly reflects differences in where
groups with different skills tend to congregate. As we have seen, over the past
three decades, jobs for college graduates have increasingly concentrated in
expensive metropolitan areas—brain hubs like San Jose, San Francisco, Boston,
New York, and Washington, D.C.—while jobs for high school graduates have
increasingly concentrated in heartland cities with a low cost of living. While
in 1980 the difference in housing costs between the two groups was small, it
has grown by more than three times. This is important, because it implies that
college graduates end up spending more for housing and therefore have less
money for other goods and services. It is as if college graduates have
experienced a higher inflation rate than high school graduates. Therefore the
difference in living standards between highly educated Americans and less
educated Americans, while large, is actually somewhat smaller than you might
think.
Post Comment
Aucun commentaire