Reducing Unemployment with Relocation Vouchers
The relative lack of mobility of less educated
Americans has large economic costs. We have seen that the changes in the global
and national economy are causing an increase in inequality among workers with
different skill levels, with the less skilled being hit the hardest.
Differences in geographical mobility, coupled with increasing polarization
among American cities, only exacerbate the problem. Thus, some of the earning
inequality between highly skilled and low-skilled workers reflects mobility
differences: if the less educated people were more able and willing to move to
cities with better job opportunities, the gap between college graduates and
high school graduates would shrink.
By being less mobile, less educated workers
are also significantly more likely to be unemployed. Figure 10 shows the
difference in unemployment rates for different educational groups over the past
twenty years. Unemployment among all groups
fluctuates, depending on the strength of the national economy. It was high in
the early 1990s, reached its lowest level at the peak of the dot-com boom in
2000, and climbed up sharply during the Great Recession of 2008–2010.
But the most interesting feature of the graph is
that in both good and bad years, college graduates—the group with the highest
mobility—have the lowest unemployment rate, while high school dropouts—the
group with the lowest mobility—consistently have the highest unemployment rate.
High school graduates and workers with a community college education are in
between. While the difference in unemployment rates reflects many factors, the
willingness to move is an important difference among the four groups. It is not
just that less educated individuals are more likely to be out of work at any
particular time; they also have to deal with the long-term consequences.
Evidence indicates that workers’ skills tend to deteriorate during long bouts
of unemployment, and this further widens the gulf between the skilled and the
unskilled.
Why does a lack of education lead to lower
mobility? For some, it reflects a dearth of information about opportunities
elsewhere, a shortage of the kinds of skills necessary to make a big life
change, and especially a lack of cash. Relocating is like an investment: you
spend money up front, to cover the direct costs of the move and your living
expenses until a job becomes available, in exchange for a better job later. But
many unemployed workers with low skills are unable to make this investment,
because they have limited savings and limited access to credit. In this case,
the lack of mobility is not a choice but the result of external constraints
that limit people’s freedom of movement. In other cases, the lower propensity
to move reflects cultural differences between the two groups. Like some
Italians, some less educated Americans choose not to move away, presumably
because they value staying near their family and friends more than better job
prospects. Although this has an economic cost, it is a perfectly legitimate
choice.
This
distinction between causes is important, because it suggests a policy reform
that could end up helping those workers whose lack of mobility is not a choice.
The unemployment insurance system, which was introduced during the 1930s, is
essentially the same now as it was then. Currently, an out-of-work person who
qualifies for unemployment insurance receives a check from the government that
covers part of his previous salary. What is striking about the system is that
it does not provide any incentive for unemployed workers to look for jobs in places
with better labor markets. If anything, it discourages mobility from
high-unemployment areas to low-unemployment ones, because it does not
compensate for the difference in cost of living. If you are living off an
unemployment check in Flint, you do not have a lot of incentives to move to
Austin to look for a new job, because your housing expenses would double but
your check would still reflect the cost of living in Flint.
The unemployment insurance system should be
adjusted to reflect the vast and growing differences in economic fortunes among
American cities. Unemployed people living in areas with above-average
unemployment rates should receive part of their unemployment insurance check in
the form of a mobility voucher that would cover some of the costs of moving to
a different area. In other words, instead of encouraging out-of-work residents
to remain in Flint, the federal government could help them relocate to Texas
(or wherever they might choose to go) with financial support that covers a
portion of their moving expenses. This would help those who would like to move
but are stuck because they lack cash.
Remarkably, this policy would also help those
who are not willing to move. The reason is simple,
although not widely recognized. If there are one thousand unemployed workers
looking for jobs in a city where there are only one hundred job openings, the
probability of each worker finding a job is one in ten. But if five hundred of
these unemployed workers are encouraged to relocate by a mobility voucher, the
probability that each of the remaining workers finds a job is doubled. In a
climate of high unemployment, the fewer people like you who are looking for a
job, the better your chances of finding one. This points to a surprising
conclusion: unemployed workers who stay in a local labor market with high
unemployment effectively impose a cost, or negative externality, on everyone
else in that market, while workers who move away generate a positive
externality. A mobility voucher is a way to deal with this. By increasing the
number of workers who are willing to relocate, the voucher benefits both those
who move, who end up with better jobs elsewhere, and those who stay, who end up
with a better chance of finding a job. (Of course, this only works for the nation
as a whole if the externality created by an unemployed worker is larger in
cities with high unemployment than in cities with low unemployment—a reasonable
assumption. Otherwise, mobility vouchers would simply shift the problem around,
with no real benefit for total unemployment.)
In practice, a mobility voucher could take the
form of an additional payment over and above the current unemployment insurance
payment for those who move out of areas with above-average unemployment. Or it
could come out of the current unemployment insurance payment, in the form of
lower benefits for those who stay (with exceptions for those with health
conditions or family constraints). The first case is a subsidy for those who
move; the second is a tax on those who stay. If people cannot move because they
don’t have savings and/or they have limited access to credit, the effect on
their mobility is likely to be larger with the first type of voucher. A
combination of the two approaches is also possible.
This idea is not completely new. The
government already provides a limited relocation allowance as part of Trade
Adjustment Assistance, an obscure federal aid program that helps workers who
have lost their jobs as a result of foreign trade. It is time to extend the
allowance to include all workers receiving unemployment insurance.
In 1968 the Harvard economist John F. Kain
proposed the theory of “spatial mismatch.” Poor
people and minorities, he argued, face a structural disadvantage in the labor
market because of the geographical mismatch between the location of housing and
the location of jobs within each city. His basic idea was that the poor tend to
be concentrated in the urban core of American cities, far from many suitable
jobs. Not only do the poor face higher commuting costs, but because they live
farther from potential employers, they also have less information about job
openings, and this further depresses their employment opportunities. Kain
argued that this geographical dislocation, combined with lower car ownership rates
and lack of efficient public transit, results in higher unemployment rates. The
sociologist William Julius Wilson embraced the notion of spatial mismatch in
his influential book The Truly Disadvantaged, which
highlighted the role of mismatch as one of the root causes of racial
differences in the United States. Effectively, the spatial mismatch theory
attributes economic inequality in part to the patterns of residential
segregation within each city.
While historically such differences may have
played a role, today it is differences across cities
that are more likely to be the source of mismatch. The divide between
well-educated workers with high-paying, secure jobs and less educated workers
with low-paying jobs is connected to the geographical divide between thriving
cities and struggling ones. In the debate over inequality in America, people
often overlook this aspect. As the gulf between the labor markets in American
cities grows, the lower propensity of less skilled workers to move becomes more
and more costly.
While the high mobility of well-educated
Americans tends to be good for their careers, it presents state governments
with a big challenge. By funding local universities and colleges, states
heavily subsidize the higher education of their residents in the hope of
fostering economic growth at the local level. In the United States, the current
subsidy to students at public universities is on the order of 80 percent. As we
saw, the overall level of human capital in an area is one of the most important
drivers of local prosperity. State legislatures’ support for higher education
is based on the hope that it will raise labor productivity and attract
innovative businesses. However, the fact that college-educated Americans are so
mobile makes the states’ efforts less effective.
A team of University of Michigan economists led
by John Bound has found that the number of degrees conferred by local colleges
and universities has only a modest effect on the number of university-educated
workers within the state. States like Michigan and
Ohio, with world-class systems of public higher education, struggle to retain
many of their college graduates, who are more drawn to opportunities in
California and New York. For the average recipients of bachelor’s degrees,
Bound and his coauthors found only a weak link between the number of students
who graduated from a state university and the number who ended up staying in
that state. For recipients of M.D. degrees, they found no connection
whatsoever: the number of doctors who stayed in Michigan had nothing to do with
the number of doctors produced by the University of Michigan. Because of the
high mobility of college graduates, the Michigan economists concluded that
states have limited power to influence the skill levels of their workforces in
a meaningful way by investing in higher education. The pull of innovation hubs
dwarfs their efforts. This is great news for the cities that attract the
college graduates—these cities effectively receive free human capital paid for
by someone else. But it significantly limits the ability of struggling states
to build a sustainable base by investing in higher education. Bound’s finding
also has interesting implications for educational policy. It suggests that the
financing of public colleges and universities should not be left solely to
states. Given that the social benefit of investment in higher education is not
contained within the borders of a state, an efficient educational policy is one
in which the federal government plays a role in supporting part of this
investment.
We now turn to another
important aspect of Americans’ mobility: its relation to real estate prices. We
have seen that there are large and growing differences in wages among American
cities. One of the primary reasons that people aren’t moving en masse to San
Francisco or Boston, despite the promise of higher wages, is that these cities
are very expensive to live in. How is cost of living affecting the Great
Divergence?
Aucun commentaire