The (Almost) Magical Economics of Knowledge Spillover
ECOtality is a company at the forefront of clean
transportation and power storage technology, which in 2010 moved its
headquarters from Arizona to the Bay Area. It is not the only one. The German
company Q-Cells, the Chinese companies Trina Solar, Suntech, and Yingli Green
Energy, and the Spanish company FRV have all recently opened shop in the Bay
Area. Clean-tech companies are increasingly locating their headquarters and/or
their R&D labs in the region. In a recent interview with the CEO of
ECOtality, NPR reported that the reason for his move was “to be close to the
action.” On some level, this makes intuitive sense.
After all, who wants to be away from the action? But on a deeper level, it
raises the question of what “being close to the action” really means. Why would
all these companies want to be so close to their competitors? What advantages
could they possibly derive?
The answer has to do with a simple fact: new
ideas are rarely born in a vacuum. Research shows that social interactions
among creative workers tend to generate learning opportunities that enhance
innovation and productivity. This flow and diffusion of knowledge represents a
crucial third advantage for workers and firms that locate within an innovation
cluster.
As we saw earlier, average education is the
most important reason that wage levels vary so much across cities. The fact
that workers earn more in brain hubs is not an accident but a reflection of the
higher labor productivity that comes from working alongside highly skilled
colleagues. The wage of the same person can be vastly different depending on
whether the people who live around him are well educated or poorly educated.
This makes sense in some general way, but it does not tell us why it is true. Understanding
exactly how and why knowledge diffuses within a circle of friends, colleagues,
or scientists in a city is vital if we want to understand why innovative
industries locate in some cities but not in others. Paul Krugman, who conducted
trailblazing academic research in this area before becoming a New York Times commentator, once famously wrote: “Knowledge
flows are invisible; they leave no paper trail by which they may be measured
and tracked, and there is nothing to prevent the theorist from assuming
anything about them that she likes.”
Krugman’s skepticism motivated many researchers
to intensify their efforts to measure the diffusion of ideas. In 1993 three
economists—Adam Jaffe, Manuel Trajtenberg, and Rebecca Henderson—found a usable
paper trail: patent citations. When filing for a
patent, an inventor is required to list all the previous inventions that her
invention builds upon. These links offered the economists an innovative way to
track the flow of knowledge among inventors. Their results were surprising:
knowledge is subject to a significant degree of “home bias,” in the sense that
inventors are significantly more likely to cite other inventors living nearby
than inventors living farther away. Because patents are freely available,
citations shouldn’t necessarily display geographical favoritism. An inventor
in, say, Durham, North Carolina, should have the same awareness of products or
ideas generated elsewhere as he does of those generated in Durham. And yet an
inventor in Durham is much more likely to cite a previous invention patented by
someone else in Durham than one patented in another city.
The magnitude of the home bias is substantial.
Excluding citations that come from the same company, citations are twice as
likely to come from the city of their citing patent than from other places. This means that scientists and inventors are more
familiar with knowledge produced by those who work near them, presumably
because they share ideas and information through informal conversations and
interactions. These interactions take place both inside and outside the
workplace, including casual settings like local cafés and social events. In
Silicon Valley, for example, weekend cricket games are known to be
opportunities not just for physical activity but also for networking and
exchange of business-related information for the local community of Indian
engineers. Increasingly, one of these engineers told the New
York Times, “cricket spills over into business.”
Geography matters for the spread of knowledge, and knowledge quickly dies with
distance. Citations are highest when the citing inventor is located between
zero and 25 miles from the cited inventor. Citations
are significantly lower when the citing inventor is more than 25 miles from the
cited inventor, and the effect completely disappears beyond 100 miles.
Geographical distance seems to impede the flow of
ideas even within the boundaries of a firm. This alone should discourage companies from outsourcing
any part of the innovation phase to low-cost countries. Take the high-tech
company Cadence, with about two thousand employees in San Jose, one thousand
workers in India, and another thousand scattered around the world. An Indian
software engineer at level T4 makes about a third of what a similarly qualified
software engineer in San Jose makes. When I asked Cadence’s executive senior
vice president, Nimish Modi, why the company does not move more R&D to
India, given the potential savings, he told me that proximity and personal
interaction matter to the creativity of its engineers. “We have sophisticated
videoconferencing facilities, and we use them all the time to communicate with
India. But it is not the same as face-to-face interaction. Nothing replaces a
group of engineers sitting together and arguing in front of the whiteboard,” he
said.
As an academic, I am not too surprised by
this. Although I communicate daily with distant colleagues by phone and e-mail,
my best ideas often occur when I least expect them—over lunch with colleagues
or at the water cooler. The reason is simple. Phone and e-mail are great ways
to transmit information and keep a research project going once the key creative
ideas are in place, but they are not the best way to come up with those ideas.
New ideas arise in mysterious and unpredictable ways from free and unstructured
interactions. It would be ridiculous to schedule a phone call with a distant
colleague to come up with a new idea. My guess is that most researchers share
this view. After all, the reason we spend so much time in academia discussing
whom to hire and fire is that our colleagues affect our own productivity.
Being around smart people tends to make us
smarter, more creative, and ultimately more productive. And the smarter the
people, the stronger the effect. Pierre Azoulay, Joshua Graff Zivin, and Jialan
Wang quantified this by focusing on what happens to medical researchers when
they work with an academic superstar. It is difficult
to establish the causal relationship here because of self-selection: superstars
tend to work with strong researchers, so the fact that their collaborators are
especially prolific may just happen because they are better, not because they
are benefiting from knowledge spillovers. To control for this, the three
economists had a smart idea. They focused on what happens to the productivity
of a superstar’s collaborators when the superstar dies unexpectedly (they
identified 112 such deaths). Although nothing changed in the collaborators’ own
circumstances following the superstars’ deaths, they experienced “a lasting 5
to 8 percent decline in their quality-adjusted publication rates.”
It is not just that people publish more when
they are close; the quality of their research is better. When a team of Harvard
Medical School doctors analyzed all medical research articles published at
Harvard and correlated their data with the distance between the authors’
offices, they found that being less than one kilometer away raised the quality
of research, as defined by how many other researchers cited the article. The effect was even larger if the authors were in the
same building or used the same elevator.
Thus innovative firms have an incentive to locate
near other innovative firms. In the same way that having a good colleague next
door affects my creativity, having good neighbors—even competitors—improves the
creativity of companies and workers. This in turn helps explain why workers in
brain hubs earn higher salaries than identical workers in other areas. There is
something almost magical in the process of generating new ideas. By clustering
near each other, innovators foster each other’s creative spirit and become more
successful. These effects have gained importance over time. While many people
think that e-mail, cell phones, and the Internet have made physical proximity
less important to the creative process, in reality the opposite is true. Location
is more important than ever, in part because knowledge spillovers are more
important than ever. This is a key reason for the accelerating divergence in
the fortunes of the three Americas.
The growing importance of knowledge spillovers
does not just affect the cities where businesses and workers are clustering. It
is also reshaping the physical layout of the workplace. Offices used to be
simple rooms with doors, until the open-space craze revolutionized the design
of many white-collar workplaces and introduced the idea of Dilbert-like
cubicles. One of the most intriguing new trends is the idea of “cowork.” Born
in California, the concept is spreading quickly through the entire country.
Cowork spaces typically host dozens (in some cases hundreds) of entrepreneurs,
innovators, and artists, who rent desks or offices in the same building and sit
next to each other. They are part of a growing number of creative professionals
in American innovation hubs who are self-employed and prefer to remain
independent of larger companies. In cowork spaces, each of them works on his
project, but the setup is appealing because it offers the possibility of
sharing ideas, building connections, and fostering creativity. It turns
isolated innovators into a real community, a creative ecosystem designed to
maximize knowledge spillovers.
One example is the San Francisco Chronicle
Building. It includes, among many other ventures, a high-tech incubator, a
school of digital filmmaking, an art gallery, a tool workshop for “inventors, makers,
hackers, tinkerers,” and hundreds of engineers, scientists, artists, and social
entrepreneurs who have decided that they have a lot to learn from each other.
When you enter one of these places, you feel more like you are at a graduate
school than in a regular office: people network, exchange tips on how to solve
technical problems, and comment on each other’s business plans. The goal is
“radical collaboration” among individuals who would otherwise be isolated,
working alone in their home offices or garages. In a
random day at the Chronicle Building, you might find a fashion designer
sketching her future hat collection next to a mechanical engineer operating a
laser cutter next to a Berkeley MBA writing a grant for a new Darfur nonprofit
organization. The creative energy is palpable. Some cowork places organize
lectures or demonstrations of the latest technologies, such as “Startup Demo
Night.” Others have happy hours and brown bag lunches with angel investors. It
is all about establishing connections and sharing insights. The phenomenon is
so new that there are no rigorous studies of how coworking affects creativity
and business success. But all the signs point in the right direction. For
example, one of the Chronicle Building’s early success stories is Square, a
mobile phone credit-card payment processing company started by Twitter
cofounder Jack Dorsey, which has grown from five to one hundred employees in
just a year.
Aucun commentaire