Why the Brain Drain Is a Good Thing
There is something phenomenal about the three
forces of attraction. They are responsible for turning a collection of
individual workers and firms into an integrated creative commons that is much
larger than the sum of its parts.
This generates what economists call localized economies of scale. The term economies
of scale usually refers to the ability of companies to become more
efficient as they grow in size. For example, large car manufacturers are more
efficient than small ones. But instead of applying to a single company, these
economies of scale apply to all the companies in a geographical area. Larger
clusters are more efficient because they have a thicker labor market, a more
specialized supply of business services, and more opportunities for knowledge
spillover. The effect can be amazing: while individual companies in a cluster
do not necessarily become more efficient as they grow in size, all companies
taken together become more efficient as the cluster grows. A surprising
implication is that as a country, the United States is more productive—and
therefore richer—because its innovation sector is concentrated in a limited
number of innovation hubs rather than spread out among all cities. This is one
of the paradoxes of our knowledge economy. The forces of attraction and the
agglomeration of economic activity create differences and inequality among
communities. But at the same time, a significant part of America’s economic
vitality and prosperity depends on them.
The three forces of attraction are further
magnified by the tendency of engineers, scientists, and innovators to leave
established companies to open their own shops. This process of procreation
exists in all industries, but it is considerably stronger in the innovation
sector, in part because employees of innovative firms tend to be a very special
group of people. They may be nerds to an outsider’s eyes, but they are
exceedingly creative and entrepreneurial. Often the very success of their
employer leads them to leave. In their early years, startups tend to have an
irreverent culture and a nonhierarchical work environment. But with success and
growth, they inevitably become more formal and less exciting, prompting some of
their most entrepreneurial employees to start their own ventures. This spawning
process is often facilitated by stock options packages, which, when vested, can
turn into seed money for a new business.
This tendency of a company’s smartest employees
to start their own ventures is often referred to as brain
drain. Companies are aware of the risk of losing their best talent and often
fight back. Intel grants sabbatical leaves. Google allows all employees to work
20 percent of the time on their own projects. When key employees threaten to
start their own ventures, Google has been known to offer them the opportunity
to start their own enterprises within Google. These perks, which are rare
outside the high-tech world, are a testament to how crucial a worker’s
creativity is in the high-tech sector and how important it is for companies to
retain good employees.
But what is costly from the point of view of an
individual company is highly beneficial for the community as a whole, because
it means more local jobs. Because of the magnetic attraction of clusters,
offspring don’t stray too far from their parents. Research shows that the reproductive
process is rarely a zero-sum game in which the young companies gain at the
expense of their elders. Instead the process ends up resulting in a net gain in
employment for the local community. And it gets even better: the children in
turn produce their own children. Thus, from the perspective of local
governments, attracting a high-tech job today will result in many more jobs in
the future.
Aucun commentaire