What This Means for the Three Americas
Several implications fall out of this new
understanding of the forces of attraction. The most important is that the
economic performances of cities will keep diverging over time. We have seen
that America’s economic map is highly uneven. At one end of the spectrum are
the brain hubs, with highly skilled and highly productive workers earning high
wages. At the other end are cities whose workers have limited skills, low
productivity, and falling wages. The divide between the different Americas is
growing with every passing year, and now we know why.
This divergence is the predictable result of the
three forces of agglomeration. These forces inevitably magnify the differences
between winners and losers among American communities. Cities with the right
sectors and with workers who have the right skills are strengthening their position,
while others, trapped by their past, are losing ground. It is a tipping-point
dynamic: once a city attracts some innovative workers and companies, its
economy changes in ways that make it even more attractive to other innovative
workers and companies. This tends to generate a self-sustaining equilibrium,
with many skilled individuals looking for innovative jobs and innovative
companies looking for skilled workers. In the end, this is why workers in
Boston are paid twice as much as workers in Flint. As the forces of
agglomeration reshape the economic map, this geographical divergence is bound
to strengthen over time.
A second implication is that once a cluster is
established, it is hard to move it. This is a case where the future of a city
depends on its past. Social scientists call it path
dependency. Take, for example, the aerospace industry, which has
historically been located near Los Angeles. In 1993 the urban planner Ann
Markusen interviewed executives at major aerospace companies, asking them why they
were located in Southern California. Their answers
were very instructive. As an official at Northrop put it, “If one was building
the first plant, one wouldn’t put it in L.A. Los Angeles would not even be in
the top ten. But there is a terrible cost to moving.” At TRW, the answer was
even more explicit: “The cost of living here is high, the traffic situation is
terrible. But we’ll probably stay here.” Because of the forces of attraction,
it was hard for the industry to relocate, even if the conditions that made Los
Angeles attractive in the first place were long gone.
This means that regions without an innovation
cluster will find it difficult to start one. It is a chicken-and-egg problem.
Specialized high-tech workers will not move to a city that does not have a
cluster because it will be hard to find an employer that values their unique
skills. High-tech companies will not move there because finding specialized
labor will be difficult. This presents a terrible challenge for communities
that have fallen on hard times and are struggling to reinvent themselves.
For the United States as a whole, however, the
implication is more favorable: it means that America’s innovation sector is to
some extent protected from foreign competition. Because of the three forces, it
is harder to delocalize innovative activity than to delocalize physical
manufacturing. A toy factory or a textile factory is a stand-alone entity that
can be put pretty much anywhere in the world where transportation is easy and
labor is abundant. In comparison, a biotech lab or an innovative high-tech
company is harder to export, because you would have to move not just one
company but an entire ecosystem. If we were starting over, I am not sure that
America today would be the most obvious candidate for the world’s innovation
hubs. But we are not starting over. America’s innovation clusters give it an
undeniable advantage over Europe, China, and India.
None of this should be an argument for
complacency. The forces of agglomeration are no guarantee that we will keep our
leadership in innovation forever. The lock-in effect in aerospace lasted for a
while, but twenty years after Markusen’s study was published, the lock-in
effect is much weaker, and the number of aerospace jobs in Los Angeles is much
smaller. As we are about to discover, all the United States has is a head
start.
Aucun commentaire